Skip to main content

Specialisation and the division of labour

Specialisation and the division of labour 

Specialisation is concentration on a product/task in order to produce it/carry it out more efficiently. It is a system of organisation where economic units such as households or nations are not self-sufficient but concentrate on producing certain goods and services and trading the surplus with others. This is in contrast to autarky/self-sufficiency. 

The division of labour is a process that allows specialisation to occur - the production procedure is broken down into a sequence of stages or tasks and workers are assigned to a particular stage. This allows for greater efficiency as each individual becomes more skilled at their particular task, more so than they ever would have been had they been doing multiple tasks. Efficiency = greater output for a given input. 

Advantages to DoL: 
As workers' skills and focus improve, they are able to produce more in a given time so productivity increases. 
Transition times are minimised as each individual is not changing from job to job. Tasks that used to have to be done in sequence can now be done simultaneously (e.g Formula 1 pitstop) 
Training time and cost decreases because workers only need to be taught a small task rather than a whole process. 

Disadvantages to DoL: 
> Worker morale and retention may decrease from doing such a repetitive job (e.g Ford had to increase wages as assembly line jobs were so boring) 
> Less satisfying work leads to boredom/alienation - may impact mental health. 
> Skills often aren't transferrable - workers lack flexibility, so may find it hard to find another job with such a limited skillset. 
> Absences/strikes can be disastrous as workers lack knowledge about tasks outside their own. Similarly there is a potential for bottleneck - one person failing at their task can ruin the whole product. 

For countries: 
> Lack of flexibility again which leads to difficulties dealing with external shocks (e.g war, product going out of fashion, etc) 
> This can lead to regions becoming deserted as factories close. 

Specialisation and trade 

Absolute advantage - a country is able to produce a good more cheaply in absolute terms than another country, so with the same factor inputs (e.g UK can produce 20 T-shirts, US can produce 30). 

Comparative advantage - a country is able to produce a good more cheaply relative to other goods produced domestically than another country (i.e the opportunity cost associated with producing the good is lower). Here it still makes sense to trade with a country that doesn't produce as much output as you because it minimises your opportunity cost. 

When two PPFs are parallel there is no comparative advantage. 
  

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Output gaps and the business cycle

Output gaps and the business cycle The fluctuation of real GDP around an underlying trend is a phenomenon known as the business cycle.  Output gap  - difference between the actual output of an economy and its potential output.  There are two types of output gap, trend and  potential.  Trend growth is the estimated rate of growth of an economy.  Trend output gaps:  Business cycle diagram A negative trend output gap is when real GDP is below trend GDP. The economy is producing below its trend.  e.g If real GDP is £1.8 trillion and trend GDP is £2 trillion then the negative output gap is £0.2 trillion.  Here the economy is in a bust  period. This is characterised by an expansion in GDP, high employment and high confidence. Price levels often rise, meaning inflation occurs.  A positive trend output gap is when real GDP is above trend GDP.  Here the economy is in a recession  (bust). This is characterised by a contraction in GDP, high unemployment and lo

3.4.1 Efficiency

Efficiency   Allocative efficiency  Output at which the marginal utility, or benefit, of a good to a consumer is the same as equal to the marginal cost of producing it.  This is seen on demand/supply curves, where D = S, output is produced as demand = marginal utility and supply = the sum of firms' marginal costs in an industry. On an individual scale, it is where:  AR = MC  Output is where the demand curve cuts the MC curve.   NB: technically occurs where MSB = MSC (if you consider externalities)  Occurs in perfect competition.  Eval - PC markets achieve allocative efficiency where there are no externalities.  LR equilibrium is where P = MPC, so if MSC > MPC, then there is an allocative inefficiency which leads to overproduction and consumption.  Productive efficiency  Output at which a good is produced at the  lowest possible average cost for a firm. This occurs at the minimum point of the AC curve.  AC = MC at this point, because w

3.3.4 Normal profits, supernormal profits and losses

Normal profits, supernormal profits and losses  Profit maximisation  Occurs at: MC = MR  where MC cuts MR from below (as where it cuts from above is point of profit minimisation)  This is because past this point MR < MC , and each additional good is costing the firm more than it is making. Before that point MR > MC so the firm can increase profit by producing more.  NB - point of prof max can be found using TC and TR:  Normal and supernormal profit and losses Normal profit is profit that covers the opportunity cost of capital and is just sufficient to keep the firm in the market.  Supernormal/economic profit are profits that exceed normal profits.  When AC lies below AR at the point of output, the difference between AR and AC is the supernormal profit on that unit output. The overall supernormal profit is the difference times the quantity sold (Q2 in the above).  Likewise, when AC lies above AR at the point of output, the company makes s